Back
to SchNEWS Home Page
Back to Bilderberg Home Page
[Page 35]
The Social and Political Impacts on Emerging Markets of Recent Economic Events
AS THE moderator argued in her introduction, the backlash
against globalisation in many developing countries has been from some
perspectives surprisingly muted. All the same the panellists argued that it was
impossible to understand either the cause or the cures of the Asian contagion
without taking into account non-financial factors, such as the quality of the
government, the integrity of the legal system and the prevalence of corruption.
Some participants thought that the West needed to put more effort into tackling
these things before lending money. Others thought the International Financial
Institutions should stick to what they know about rather that engage in
broad-ranging social engineering.
FIRST PANELLIST
There are plenty of important non-financial things that have
contributed to the spread of the Asian crisis, and also must be part of any
cure. These begin with the quality of government: a $57 billion aid package is
unlikely to be successful if the government is incompetent and corrupt. Another
challenge is the legal system. Countries with property rights and good
bankruptcy systems have a much better chance of surviving the storm than those
that do not. Many countries sell jobs as judges to the highest bidder: in the
Caucuses, for example, many of the wealthiest people are all judges. Then there
is the regulatory framework, and finally, the social safety net.
The people who suffer most from economic dislocation are almost
always the poor. In Russia as many as 50 million people live on less than $4 a
day. Two hundred thousand people have been thrown out of work in the coal mines,
threatening social
[Page 36]
unrest. In South Korea, the poor are still suffering, and the
biggest need there is for more structural reform. South Korea was enormously
lucky that it elected a reforming president just before the financial system
collapsed. Kim used his opportunities to push through structural reform and even
set up a social safety net in Korea. Kim now faces an even more intractable
problem: the fact that the economy has bounced back without the reform program
being completed.
No reform program will be complete without the active
participation of business. Seven years ago $30 billion a year flowed into
emerging markets. Last year the figure was $300 billion. Engaging business is
not just a matter for theoretical debate. It is crucial.
SECOND PANELLIST
The International Monetary Fund is controlled by 24 executive
directors, eight from single countries, the rest from groups of countries.
Countries vote in proportion to the number of shares they control in the
organisation: the United States has 18% of the votes, the G7 has half, meaning
that a united West cannot really lose a vote. Everything the IMF does is voted
on. But contested votes are rare: decisions are by consensus, with the consensus
usually put together outside the boardroom. The IMF's legitimacy results
from the fact that it was established by international treaty with more or less
universal membership. It sticks very close to its original articles of
agreement.
Corruption is a huge problem in the Fund's work. In Kenya,
for example, hundreds of millions of dollars worth of reserves have been paid
out to businessmen and politicians. The IMF clearly cannot lend developing
countries money if is likely to be stolen; but without IMF loans their economies
are likely to decline still further. Before giving a large loan to Indonesia the
Fund had to deal with corruption, particularly the forestation fund, which
represented 2% of GDP but had never been properly accounted for in the budget
and provided the president's family with monopolies. Was the Fund's
decision to fight corruption
[Page 37]
destabilising? Perhaps. But the real cause of instability was
the system itself.
The International Financial Institutions are facing increasing
pressure to use their might to democratise countries. They should not just
consult with the government, they are being told, but with interest groups of
all descriptions. They are increasingly responding to this pressure. But is it
really their job to get countries to accept values and standards that are not
rooted in economics? Pushing for the implementation of the International
Declaration of Human Rights, for example, is very far from the traditional role
of financial institutions.
THIRD PANELLIST
The best way to solve the economic and social problems
associated with crises maybe to prevent boom-bust cycles from happening. In
America, where these cycles have successfully been resisted, high school
dropouts are extraordinary successful at getting new jobs. Boom-bust cycles are
particularly bad for emerging markets. The poor are hardest hit. There is no
safety net to catch them when they fall. And the middle class is devastated. We
were very lucky that a highly capable, democratic leader came to power in South
Korea when he did.
The countries that went under in the financial crisis all have
one thing in common: very weak banking systems. As Schumpeter pointed out, the
only institution that is really essential to a capitalist economy is a bank:
banks act as shock absorbers and workout specialists during recessions. But in
Asia's command economy the government simply told bankers what to do. In a
meeting of bankers in South Korea in April, 1998, it rapidly became clear that
none of the bankers in the room had any idea what a "workout loan"
was: they had never made a credit judgement and had no idea how to work with a
troubled customer.
Banking is a very difficult business to learn. The best way to
learn it is to let foreign banks come into you country. Argentina was perhaps
the first country to do this. Argentine banking fami-
[Page 38]
lies now send their children to foreign banks so that they can
learn the latest banking methodologies before they return to the local bank. The
other thing that is crucial is the rule of law: you need to be able to collect
on your loans. In the United States you can take ownership of collateral
property in three months; in Mexico it can take a minimum of three-and-half
years -- and in that time your investment has probably deteriorated
hopelessly.
DISCUSSION
An early theme to the discussion was the fate of globalisation
as an ideology. A Swiss participant pointed out that the Uruguay Round had ended
up in a very different -- and very much more pro-market -- climate than it
had begun; now, he warned, the climate seemed to be changing again, with
right-wing governments losing power around the world. He wondered what could be
done to co-opt emerging countries into the system. A panellist replied that the
reason why countries find the transition to the market economy difficult is not
usually ideological -- anti-market ideology is dying out in much of the
world, and has almost completely disappeared in Latin America -- but lack of
competence, particularly in putting together a financial and legal system that
works.
For one Swedish participant, confidence was the key. In most
countries, there is plenty of private capital available. But no one will invest
their capital unless they have confidence in the institutional framework of the
countries in which they are investing. Indeed, lack of confidence promotes
capital flight: there is thirty times more Russian capital outside the country
than inside the country.
Several other participants emphasised the importance of fighting
corruption. An Italian pointed out that Europeans are often too shy about
fighting corruption in their own backyards: in some European countries bribes
are tax deductible. A Canadian thought it a little odd to make the International
Financial Institutions the main vehicle for fighting corruption and imposing the
rights of labour, when non-governmental organisations already have an
[Page 39]
impressive track record in fighting for these causes.
The problem of Russia aroused a good deal of comment. A French
participant argued that the West bore a good deal of responsibility for
Russia's situation. It had encouraged Russia to jump into a free-market
system that it had taken forty years for Western Europe to embrace. Perhaps we
should recognise that we do not need a perfect world in order to do business, he
argued. But most participants were less sympathetic. A Swede pointed out that
much of the money sent to Russia has been squandered. The state of the coal
industry, for instance, is not primarily a social problem, he argued, but a
problem of organised crime. An American asked whether there would ever come a
point at which the West would decide to stop lending money to Russia. Yes,
replied one of the panellists, the West has said enough is enough in August
1998; but the West has a continuing interest in tying Russia into the
international financial system.
However, the main focus of the discussion was the degree to
which outsiders -- particularly the international financial
institutions -- could intervene in the non-financial affairs of borrowers. A
Finnish banker pointed out that it has been standard practice in the academic
community for years to take into account social and political factors. A
Portuguese participant emphasised the importance of having a "social
argument" with all the major partners in economic life.
But others were more sceptical. A Swedish banker pointed out
that for his profession, the state of the legal system was simply part of credit
risk. An American argued that it could be a huge mistake to interfere in
political issues: the IMF should meddle only in areas where it has the
expertise, such as banking. In South Korea, for instance, the struggle between
the chaebol and the politicians has been a long-standing political issue, and
the IMF interfered at its peril. A Canadian saw even more limitations in taking
a "holistic" approach. Should the private sector really be involved
with labour organisations and religious organisations? And should businesspeople
try to double up as social missionar-
[Page 40]
ies? He worried that this policy would make the West enormously
vulnerable to demagogues. It might even create a "matrix of
colonialism".
In their conclusions, some of the panellists defended the idea
that the West had the right to demand higher standards. The first panellist
pointed out that in places like Azerbaijan, Armenia and Georgia the discussion
has not been about the West imposing something: it had been asked to provide
help and give the benefit of its experience. Fighting corruption had got huge
domestic support in these countries: in Georgia, for example, the government had
put the exams for judgeships on television to prove that the system was being
cleaned up. The battle against corruption is not an overnight thing. And it
needs to be built around the traditions of the countries concerned. But, in his
view, it was certainly not a matter of imposing foreign values.
|